It is so easy to get caught up in the details of the debate about the future of Social Security that the most fundamental point is often overlooked. The most fundamental point is this: Social Security is, and was intended to be, a program of SOCIAL INSURANCE, not a program of INDIVIDUAL INVESTMENT. This is not just a game of words. Indeed, understanding the difference between these two ideas is the key to having even a glimmer of understanding about what is at stake in this huge public debate.
To illustrate the difference, I will look at two aspects in turn. First I'll explain the difference between INSURANCE and INVESTMENT. Then I'll look at the difference between SOCIAL and INDIVIDUAL.
INSURANCE versus INVESTMENT
When you invest money – for retirement or anything else – it makes sense to evaluate your investment in terms of what you get out of it, or your “rate of return.” After all, that is why people invest money: to make more money. Unless you are a philanthropist, an investment that leaves you with less money than you started with is a bad deal, and you would be a fool to pursue such an investment.
After years of propaganda, most public assessments of the value of the Social Security program start from this premise: How good a “deal” is it, in terms of what you “get back” on your “investment.” For example, my local paper the Star Tribune (Newspaper of the Twin Cities!) on a recent Sunday ran a major feature on the Social Security debate, headlined, “Social Security: What's at Stake?” The very first sentence of this “analysis” piece (and you can find similar ones in the major media anywhere you look) reads like this: “Social Security looks like a good deal to Robert Potter.”
The article points out that “Over the years, Potter, 57, has paid about $155,000 in Social Security taxes. When he retires, he'll collect about $23,000 a year in Social Security benefits.” Therefore, it's obvious to the Star Trib that this is a “good deal” to Potter, since he looks to “get back what he paid out in about seven years.” This way of evaluating Social Security is so common that it likely doesn't seem strange to most readers. Let me point out how strange it is.
This sort of “analysis” only makes sense if you think of Social Security as a system of investment. Why is that strange? Because, as I said above, the program was never intended to be an investment program.
If you think of Social Security as a system of insurance – which it is – then this “good deal/bad deal” line of thinking makes no sense at all. Here's why: With insurance, you only get something back if you lose something. I hope I never collect anything on my home insurance, for example, since that would mean my house has burned down, or some other horrible thing has happened. Still, I pay my home insurance premium every year and I don't think I am wasting my money. Why not? Because I know that, if and when I do lose something, I have insurance. If I never “get back what I paid in,” that's a good thing. And, if I lose something, and DO get back some of what I paid in, what I get back is related to what I lost, not to what I paid in. And that, too, is a good thing. That's the nature of insurance. It's not the nature of investment.
SOCIAL versus INDIVIDUAL
Insurance, even in it's most commercial form, is a social program. That is, it is based on what we know, as opposed to what we don't know. What we know are aggregate numbers, or social statistics. To use the example of my home insurance, what we know is roughly how many houses are going to burn down in a given year. What we don't know is which ones they will be. So, we insure the group. Everyone, then, who wants to be in the insured group agrees to pay a premium that amounts to their proportionate share of the costs of replacing all of the homes that will burn down this year, not knowing whether or not one of them will be their own.
When you are part of an insurance “pool,” what you get in exchange for your premium is two things: you get to express solidarity with your neighbors and fellow insurees by paying your share of the social costs of property replacement, and you get the security of knowing that, should you have a loss, all of your neighbors will share in the costs of replacing what was lost, and you won't have to bear the burden yourself.
That, in fact, is the essence of insurance: Everyone chips in to help out those who lose something. If it is standard insurance, we chip in by paying “premiums.” If it is Social Security, we chip in by paying taxes. What is the loss that Social Security is intended to insure us against? It's the loss of wages, or income, due to old age, death, or disability. (The program is sometimes referred to as “OASDI,” for “Old Age, Survivors, and Disability Insurance.”)
The essence of the social insurance program known as Social Security is that it's a deal between the generations, where those who are working chip in to help those who are not, knowing that the same giving will come their way when the time comes.
Now, in the world of commercial insurance, there is also the matter of making a profit for shareholders, who care not about solidarity, but about self-enrichment. For them it is an investment, which introduces the tremendous irony of having people investing in other people's bad luck, which turns out to be a sort of “anti-solidarity.” That's an important issue, but is not our concern at the moment.
It's not our concern because making a profit is not part of the Social Security program. Unlike commercial insurance, Social Security enriches no individual, nor is it supposed to. It is a social program, the success of which is based on how well it protects all of its participants against the loss of income. And, for the past 70 years or so, it's protected people fairly well. (I think it could be a lot better, but that, too, is not our concern at the moment.)
At the moment, all I ask is that you consider whether you prefer a system of INDIVIDUAL INVESTMENT – such as the one being pushed by Mr. Bush and his allies – which says that some people can get a “good deal” even when some of their neighbors are getting a “bad deal.” Or do you prefer a system of SOCIAL INSURANCE – such as the current system of Social Security – in which everyone pays in a proportional share and everyone receives in return the security of knowing that they are protected against poverty and deprivation?
When you strip away all of the charts, and the graphs, and actuarial debates, and the endless parade of numbers in the billions and trillions, this is the fundamental issue in the debate about Social Security. |